European fiscal responses to the Covid-19 crisis: share the bonds or split the bill?

Jérôme
Creel
, Paul
Hubert
, Xavier Ragot and
Francesco Saraceno

The lock-down of most EU countries, in response
to the Covid-19 pandemic, has produced disruptions in the production process
and has put consumption and investment to a halt. Against the backdrop of these
supply and demand shocks, EU member states have implemented different public policies: they have deferred or waived tax
payments and social security contributions; they have raised spending towards
the health sector; and they have provided more generous welfare payments to
short-term working schemes. Quite strikingly, EU fiscal cooperation has stalled
and no common European initiative has emerged, with the exception of a
temporary lift of the fiscal constraints of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP)
(the escape clause has been activated) and a softening of State Aid
regulations. Yet, various policy proposals coping with the economic and budget
consequences of the pandemic at the European level have flourished:
Coronabonds, recourse to the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), the SURE
initiative by the European Commission, and monetisation of public debt are all
widely debated. This post lists the proposals and highlights their respective potential
benefits and shortcomings.



The SURE Unemployment Mechanism

The European Commission announced on April 2 2020 its
proposition of a mechanism to support Member States in their attempt to deal
with the surge of labour market related expenditures (unemployment subsidies, temporary
unemployment, etc). The initiative of the European Commission to support Member
States in designing short-term work arrangements is important politically.

The Support to mitigate Unemployment Risks in
an Emergency (SURE), should take the form of a loan program to member states,
modelled on the functioning of the predecessor of the ESM, the EFSF created in
2010 to provide assistance to Member States in financial distress. The legal
basis of SURE, which the Commission sees as “ad hoc and temporary”, is Article
122 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (‘TFEU’), which
states that a Member state in trouble because of exceptional circumstances may
seek financial assistance from the EU. Like the ESFF, the facility would raise
funds on financial markets (at preferential rates), guaranteed by capital
guarantees provided by governments; these could be passed on to Member states
that have a lower credit rating and face higher financing costs. Article 122
has been conceived for asymmetric shocks, and SURE would be the first instance
in which it is used to shield Member states from a symmetric shock.

SURE is capped to €100bn (0.8 % of the Eurozone
GDP), and the amount obtained by each member is undefined (although caps are
defined). Article 6 of the proposed regulation simply says that following the
request by the Member State, the amount, pricing and maturity are decided by
the Commission, after it has assessed the extent of public expenditures
directly related to the creation of “short-time work scheme and similar
measures for the self-employed” (page 7 of the Regulation proposal). Guarantees
(“irrevocable, unconditional and on demand”) to the Fund are given by Member
states based on their share of GNI of the Union, on a voluntary basis, for an
amount of at least 25% of the total amount lent; the instrument will not become
fully operational until all countries contributed.

While it was presented as a solidarity scheme,
with a subliminal reference to a pan-European unemployment scheme, SURE is not
such a thing. It is simply a loan scheme, aimed at ensuring that the recipient
country obtains reasonable interest rates. Its capacity to be a game changer,
therefore, will eventually depend on the size of loans actually available for a
given country. And this is where the problems begin.

The Commission has designed the proposed Regulation
to ensure its financial viability, and with the priority of protecting its
standing as a good quality borrower. The total amount available for loans will
therefore depend on the guarantees. The €100bn will be reached only if
countries commit to guarantee 25% of that amount. Furthermore, caps to each
Member quota (the three largest loans cannot exceed 60% of the total), strongly
limit the amount of funds available for each country.

Let’s just make an example, taking the most
favourable case. Suppose that Member states pledge enough guarantees to reach
the full fund capacity of €100bn, which is far from obvious. If we take the two
countries that most likely will need the fund, Italy and Spain, and we assume
that they manage to ensure 25% each of that amount (remember that there is a
60% limit on the three largest loans) , this will make a loan of €25bn.
Assuming furthermore that this will yield a savings in interest payments equal
to the current spread (190 and 115 for Italy and Spain respectively as of April
4), we are talking about €475 and 287 million (0.03% and 0.02% of GNI)
respectively. An amount that will hardly make any difference in the current
situation, even abstracting from the fact that Italy and Spain will have to
commit in guarantees €2.7 and 1.9bn respectively (corresponding to the
respective quotes of EU GNI of 11% and 7.6%).

To summarize, SURE is a tool to provide Member
states with extra resources without the conditionality that would be involved
in other instruments such as the ESM (see next). The extra resources would come
from interest payment savings. SURE is not, as might be understood at first
sight, a mutual insurance tool. As such, it has no resemblance to existing proposal for unemployment (re)insurance
schemes
, although
it may be argued that it is a first decisive step towards a permanent European
unemployment  benefit scheme (Vandenbroucke et al., 2020). The most apparent flaw of SURE is its firepower. The €100bn
advertised are an upper bound unlikely to be reached in practice. And the
boundaries set to preserve the borrower rating of the Commission will severely
limit the amount of fresh resources quickly usable by the Member countries that
need them most.

A Special ESM Covid Credit line

A number of European economists have proposed the
creation of a Covid credit line within the ESM. This would have the
advantage of requiring no new institution, as the credit line could be created
by the ESM Board of Directors (article 19 of the ESM Treaty) as a new financial assistance
instrument. Contrary to existing ESM credit lines, the Covid credit line would
consist in very long-term loans (that the ESM should finance issuing bonds of
equally long maturity), so as to avoid that countries are forced to repay when
still in financial distress.

The ESM firepower is large but not unlimited.
It is currently €410bn (3,4 % of the Eurozone GDP), which is most likely going
to be insufficient in view of the challenges created by the pandemic. If that
amount had to be scaled up, additional guarantees by Eurozone countries would
have to be called in.

According to the authors, the creation of a
special line would allow to avoid the most serious and controversial shortcoming
of current ESM lending: stigma for countries applying for it and heavy
conditionality. The Covid credit line would involve very little conditionality,
just a commitment to spend the resources in Covid related expenditures.

Like for SURE, ESM financing involves very
little risk sharing, as borrowing from the Mechanism adds to domestic sovereign
debt. This is why it is today the most preferred option for core eurozone
countries. And like SURE, its main advantage is that it would shield
financially fragile Member countries by allowing them access to preferential
interest rates.

The main problem with the Covid credit line is
that being created within the ESM, it is organized by the same normative
framework that rules the other credit lines. ESM lending reposes on two
principles. The first, introduced in the Treaties following the creation of the
ESM in 2012, states that financial assistance to Member States “will be made
subject to strict conditionality” (Article 136(3) of the TFEU). The second principle, introduced
by one of the two regulations that make up the Two pack (No 472/2013, Art7(5)) states that the Council, acting on
a proposal by the Commission, can decide on changes to be made on a programme.
This means that whatever conditionality is agreed upon right now, in the
framework of the new Covid line, may be changed unilaterally by the creditors
later along the road. If the Covid line were to be agreed at the Eurogroup,
together with the light conditionality proposed by Benassy-Quéré et al (2020), changes would have to be made to
the normative framework to make it sure that such conditionality cannot be
changed later on, once things “go back to normal”.

Another potential problem of embedding the
Covid credit line within the ESM is that the latter is an intergovernmental
institution that has been agreed upon by Eurozone governments alone. The Covid
credit line would in principle only be available to them. Given the global
nature of the current pandemic, cutting out non-Eurozone countries would be
unthinkable. Therefore, even if it was possible to credibly commit to light
conditionality, the Covid line could not be the foundation of the European
joint effort.

Coronabonds as temporary Eurobonds

A group of German economists has proposed the implementation of
a common debt instrument at the Eurozone level. Such “Coronabonds” would be
jointly issued under shared liability. The amount issued would be of or
€1,000bn (8 % of Eurozone’s GDP) and a key feature of these Coronabonds for
their political feasibility in the short-run would be their limitation to the
current crisis period as a one-off measure.

The
liabilities for Coronabonds being shared, national sovereign debts would only increase
proportionally to the share of each country’s GDP in the euro area (equivalent
to the ECB capital key). The maturity of Coronabonds should be as long as
possible, and the interest payments being based again on ECB capital key, it
would imply a mutualisation of borrowing costs. In a more ambitious scheme, member
states that are the most severely affected and for which sovereign financing
conditions are the tightest could benefit in priority from these funds, but
this would involve more than just a mutualisation of borrowing costs, its
timely feasibility being greatly reduced.

The
question of the guarantees for these Coronabonds is key since they would most
likely finance other expenditures than infrastructures that could act as
collateral. They could be purchased by the ECB under PEPP (not at issuance, which
is currently not legally possible, but on the secondary market). The ECB self-imposed
issuer limit for supranational securities is 50% normally, but does not apply
to PEPP holdings, and there would be no capital key to respect. In an extreme
case, even an issuer limit of 99% would be legal: the EU Court of Justice in
2018 made the point that ECB purchases are legal as long as the ECB is “not
permitted to buy either all the bonds issued by such an issuer or the entirety
of a given issue of those bonds”.

The issuance of Coronabonds could be organised
by an existing institution like the ESM or the European Investment Bank (EIB)
so it would not entail creating a new legal framework or require a change in
the EU Treaty. Under these conditions, this framework would be operational
quickly as the crisis requires. Another advantage of such Coronabonds is that
they would act as a “safe asset” that could be used by Eurozone banks as
collateral and would reduce the probability of a vicious circle between banks
and governments as experienced during the 2012-2015 sovereign debt crisis. The
main drawback of this proposition relates to its political feasibility and
whether countries that opposed Eurobonds would not oppose such mutualisation of
borrowing costs as well.

Perpetual bonds or debt monetisation: the
solution of last resort?

The ECB has committed to being the lender of
last resort of banks, e.g. through favourably-priced long term refinancing
operation (LTROs) at the negative deposit facility rate, and it has extended
the Asset Purchase Programme by €120bn, then by an additional €750bn a few days
later with the temporary Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEPP). Yet, the
ECB has not become the de jure lender
of last resort for euro area Member States. The current health, economic and
financial crisis requires strong fiscal stimuli but the rise of public debt to
GDP ratio in highly indebted euro area countries, like Italy and France, raises
doubts on their debt sustainability. To mitigate the risk of debt
unsustainability, two additional proposals have been put forth recently.

Giavazzi and
Tabellini (2020)
advocate the issuance of perpetual Covid Eurobonds to fund
the necessary rise in public spending and decline in tax revenues that the
pandemic is generating in the euro area. Most characteristics of perpetual
bonds resemble those of the Coronabonds, except that the capital of the former
would never be redeemed. The Covid Eurobonds would be backed by the joint tax
capacity of euro area Member states. Each country would issue the amount of
Covid Eurobonds depending on its funding needs, but all bonds would be the
same. If the ECB committed to purchasing these Covid Eurobonds on secondary
markets, it would make their yield minimal. In the actual low rate environment,
Giavazzi and Tabellini argue that the yield on these bonds could be low as well
– they take the example of a yield of 0.5% – and that overall funding could
easily outweigh all other European funding instruments. The initiative for European Renaissance Bonds is very close to Covid Eurobonds in
its spirit. In contrast though, the Renaissance bonds would finance a common,
centralized fund under the responsibility of the Union’s institutions (e.g. the
Commission), and would not raise national debts. In contrast with other
discussed Coronabonds or Covid Perpetual Bonds, Renaissance bonds would be
entirely mutualized within the dedicated fund. Risk-sharing would be heightened,
as well as European solidarity.

De Grauwe (2020) does not propose the
creation of a new fund, a new financial instrument or the extension of a credit
line out of an existing institution (like the ESM). Instead, he advocates that
the ECB and the EU cross the Rubicon and accept that the former purchases the
public debts of the latter on the primary markets, hence at debt issuance.
While this would require either a Treaty change – the second indent of Article
132(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union forbids monetary
financing – or much agility (or ingenuity to take De Grauwe’s word) of public
lawyers, this is not impossible to achieve as the recent example of the Bank of
England shows
, at
least on a temporary basis. First and foremost, the current context is
exceptional and requires exceptional measures. Second, what was considered
impossible in the past has finally been possible: the development of non-standard
policies by the ECB in 2008 with the Fixed Rate Full Allotment for the main
refinancing operations is one example. With the acceleration of the so-called
European sovereign debt crisis, the ECB has done “whatever it takes to preserve
the euro”. With the creation in 2012 of the not-yet-used Outright Monetary
Transactions programme (OMT), then the Assets Purchase Programme (APP), the ECB
has acted de facto as the lender of
last resort of euro area Member States. De Grauwe’s argument would lift a
contradiction between the behaviour of the ECB and the absence of a de jure lender
of last resort in the euro area (Creel 2018): debt monetization would make it clear that,
as in the US, the UK or Japan to name only a few, the central bank is the
lender of last resort not only of banks but also of States. To cope with the
health, economic and social costs of the pandemic, debt monetization through
secondary markets would have to be applied by all EU central banks, and not
only by the ECB.

The main risk with debt monetization though is
inflation. In the current circumstances, with the demand shock that seems to
dominate the supply shock and with oil prices collapsing, this is not likely.
Yet, if it happened, it would be welcome with joy at central banks which target
inflation and which are unable to fulfil their mandates in this respect. That
being said, debt monetization may be limited to newly-issued public bonds funding
the fiscal response to Covid-19 in the Member States. This would give them
almost unlimited fiscal margins for maneuver to dampen the crisis, without any
risk of seeing the spreads resurface between the core and the peripheral
countries of the euro area. Finally, long awaited inflation after debt
monetization would also alleviate the real debt burden, a characteristic shared
after most episodes of war-accumulated debts.

The second risk of debt monetization is the ECB
balance sheet risk it embeds, via the ECB backing of domestic fiscal policies. The
balance sheet risk is shared by all eurozone countries proportionally to ECB
capital keys. A temporary debt monetization conditional on the funding of
Covid-19 related expenditures or tax deference would not neutralize this kind
of risk, but it would limit it to exceptional circumstances.

Another substantial risk of debt monetization,
and of any form of debt mutualisation, is the moral hazard it could generate.
For instance, the ECB could actually back possibly inappropriate fiscal
policies. Here again, a temporary debt monetization conditional on the funding
of Covid-19 related expenditures or tax deference would not totally neutralize
moral hazard, but this one is very limited in the current Covid-19 context,
where the nature of fiscal policy as a necessary support to the economy is uncontroversial.
As a consequence, any temporary policy mechanism during this crisis period is unlikely
to generate wrong incentives.

Finally, it is useful to provide an order of
magnitude of the transfer to a European country of the most favourable financial
scheme of debt mutualisation. Assume, as an example, that public debt increases
by 10 points of 2019 GDP (public debt over GDP will increase at much higher
level due to the fall in GDP). With the spread between Germany and Italy currently
at 200 basis points, funding Italian public debt at the German interest rate
would save 0.2 point of 2019 GDP, hence €36 bn. In addition, it may be possible
that the interest rate on other countries’ debts increase a little. The ensuing
redistributive effect would thus help countries most affected by the Covid-19
crisis, which have substantial borrowing needs.